Abstract
In the past six decades, lifespan inequality has varied greatly within and among countries even while life expectancy has continued to increase. How and why does mortality change generate this diversity? We derive a precise link between changes in age-specific mortality and lifespan inequality, measured as the variance of age at death. Key to this relationship is a young–old threshold age, below and above which mortality decline respectively decreases and increases lifespan inequality. First, we show for Sweden that shifts in the threshold’s location have modified the correlation between changes in life expectancy and lifespan inequality over the last two centuries. Second, we analyze the post–World War II (WWII) trajectories of lifespan inequality in a set of developed countries—Japan, Canada, and the United States—where thresholds centered on retirement age. Our method reveals how divergence in the age pattern of mortality change drives international divergence in lifespan inequality. Most strikingly, early in the 1980s, mortality increases in young U.S. males led to a continuation of high lifespan inequality in the United States; in Canada, however, the decline of inequality continued. In general, our wider international comparisons show that mortality change varied most at young working ages after WWII, particularly for males. We conclude that if mortality continues to stagnate at young ages yet declines steadily at old ages, increases in lifespan inequality will become a common feature of future demographic change.
Introduction
Lifespan inequality is the defining measure of social and health disparity. Alongside life expectancy (the mean age at death), lifespan inequality is a key indicator of population health (Edwards and Tuljapurkar 2005; Tuljapurkar et al. 2000). Changes in life expectancy are well understood in terms of the underlying changes in mortality: mortality reduction at any age increases life expectancy (Goldman and Lord 1986; Keyfitz 1977; Vaupel 1986; Vaupel and Canudas-Romo 2003). However, the precise link between lifespan inequality and age-specific mortality is less clear. First, only mortality decline at ages below a young–old threshold can decrease lifespan inequality (van Raalte and Caswell 2013; Vaupel et al. 2011; Zhang and Vaupel 2009). Second, there are several ways to quantify lifespan inequality and understand its change through time (Cheung et al. 2005; Edwards and Tuljapurkar 2005; Horiuchi et al. 2008; Vaupel et al. 2011; Wilmoth and Horiuchi 1999). Although highly correlated, these measures behave differently in response to change in the age structure of mortality (van Raalte and Caswell 2013). Here, we measure lifespan inequality by the variance of age at death, which measures the dispersion in age at death relative to life expectancy (Edwards and Tuljapurkar 2005). The variance of age at death is a central parameter in population and economic modeling (Caswell 2009; Edwards 2012; Schindler et al. 2012; Tuljapurkar 2008; Tuljapurkar and Edwards 2011); therefore, understanding how it responds to mortality change is important. We present an exact relationship between age-specific mortality and the variance of age at death (upcoming Eq. (2)), which is a more transparent and demographically interpretable relationship than that derived by Caswell (2009:equation (2)). Our framework provides a powerful tool for quantifying how trajectories of age-specific mortality affect the variance, both within countries and in an international sample of countries.
Given period age-specific mortality, μ(x), and the corresponding probability of survival to each age l(x), the age-distribution of death is φ(x) = μ(x)l(x). Figure 1 contrasts the age distribution of death in Sweden in 1800 and 2000, illustrating the standard outcomes of development: (1) reduction of child death; (2) increase of life expectancy; (3) emergence and advance of a modal age at adult death; and (4) decrease of lifespan inequality (Bongaarts 2005; Canudas-Romo 2008; Lee and Carter 1992; Vaupel et al. 2011). These outcomes arise from an initial focus of mortality decline on children and young adults, followed by a shift of mortality decline to older ages (Cutler et al. 2006).
Since about 1950 in the developed countries, life expectancy has increased consistently, but change in lifespan inequality among countries has varied greatly (Edwards and Tuljapurkar 2005; Engelman et al. 2010; Peltzman 2009; Smits and Monden 2009). This is in striking contrast to the strong negative correlation between changes in life expectancy and lifespan inequality present during the first century of mortality decline (Vaupel et al. 2011). The recent variability of this relationship, we show, results from the very different responses of life expectancy and lifespan inequality to age-specific mortality change. First, we show that in Sweden, the threshold for the variance of age at death increased from childhood in the late eighteenth century to approximately 65 years in 1950 (solid line in Fig. 3). This movement of the threshold altered the relationship between changes in life expectancy and lifespan inequality. Second, we examine the pattern of post–WWII lifespan inequality across many countries, and then focus on Japan, Canada, and the United States. The application of our decomposition to these postwar trajectories of lifespan inequality shows that fluctuations in lifespan inequality resulted primarily from mortality change at young working ages.
Results
The Analysis of Change
Hereafter, we refer to the rate of change in Eq. (2) as the sensitivity of V(A). Panel a of Fig. 2 shows the sensitivity of the variance for A = 15, for Sweden in 1950 and 2011. Three features of the plot are typical of mortality in developed countries: (1) mortality decline at ages from 15 to about 65 years decreases V; (2) mortality decline after about 65 years increases V; and (3) there is a threshold age, T(15), at approximately 65 years, that separates “young” ages (at which mortality decline decreases V) from “old” ages (at which mortality decline increases V). The sensitivity of life expectancy e(15) to a proportional mortality decline at age x (Goldman and Lord 1986; Vaupel 1986; Vaupel and Canudas-Romo 2003) is shown for comparison in Fig. 2, panel b. The obvious distinctions are that mortality decline at any age increases life expectancy and that mortality decline close to the threshold has least effect on V. The great difference in the shape of these sensitivities of life expectancy and lifespan inequality—especially below the threshold age—is the critical factor driving their divergent responses to the same age structure of mortality change.
Long-Term Mortality Change
Sweden was the first country to record ages at death systematically, with records from 1751 to 2011 (Human Mortality Database 2012). These data provide the best opportunity to understand the long-term association of the young–old threshold with changes in lifespan inequality. Figure 3 displays the annual change in the thresholds T(A), for index ages A = 0, 15, and 65 years. Figure 4 shows the concurrent changes in e(A) and V(A).
Before about 1875 in Sweden, the threshold T(0) followed a fluctuating increase to about 20 years (Fig. 3), so only mortality decline in children and very young adults could decrease V. However, V(0) changed little (Fig. 4, panel a), indicating an even distribution of mortality decline below and above the threshold age. From 1875 to about 1950, the threshold advanced to nearly 60 years, so mortality decline at a greater range of young ages could then decrease V. This reinforced the strong negative correlation between changes to life expectancy and lifespan inequality. In this period, V decreased rapidly, and life expectancy increase accelerated, indicating much faster mortality declines below the threshold age. After 1950, the threshold continued advancing to 70–75 years. In this recent period, decreases in V slowed despite continued increases in life expectancy, indicating the switch to more even mortality decline below and above the threshold age.
Increasing the index age after which we measure lifespan inequality advances the young–old threshold. To investigate changes in lifespan inequality among adults, we use an index of 15 years. V(15) did not begin to decrease rapidly until ca. 1925 (Fig. 4, panel b), when the threshold T(15) was 57 years (Fig. 3). That this decrease began about 50 years later than the decrease in V(0) indicates the much later spread of rapid mortality decline from below 15 years to 15–57 years. By 1950, mortality reduction below 15 years had converged the thresholds T(0) and T(15) to 60–65 years. This initiated a period when the distribution of mortality change between working and retired ages was critical in shaping the trajectory of lifespan inequality.
Consider now an index age of 65 years: the obvious feature of mortality change is the consistent positive relationship of changes in life expectancy and lifespan inequality (Fig. 4, panel c). The threshold T(65) was always near 70 years, so only mortality decline at a few young ages could decrease V(65). Therefore, even with mortality reduction by an equal proportion at each age, there was a strong bias for variance increase. The only deviation occurred after 1980, when the trajectory of V(65) flattened while e(65) increased; the threshold was 75 years in 1980. Comparison of mortality change at ages 65–75 years and >75 years showed an abrupt increase in mortality decline among males, which was greatest at 65–75 years (Fig. S1 in Online Resource 1). This decline, which was large enough to overwhelm the bias for variance increase, disrupted the positive correlation between increases in life expectancy and lifespan inequality for the first time since 1751.
The Young–Old Threshold for Mortality in Developed Countries
Age-Specific Drivers of Lifespan Inequality Change in Developed Countries
We now focus on the post–WWII changes to V(15) in developed countries, for which the young–old threshold was near ages 60–70. Our analysis shows that changes in lifespan inequality were shaped by striking differences in mortality change for young versus old adults. We begin with a brief international overview: Fig. 5 (solid lines) shows the average trajectories of V(15) for each sex across 40 regional data series from the Human Mortality Database (Vaupel et al. 2011). V(15) fluctuated more for males, and the annual directions of V(15) change were also less regionally consistent in males (Fig. S2, Online Resource 1). Our decomposition (dashed lines) showed that the variance effects of mortality change at young ages (below the threshold) fluctuated more than at old ages (above the threshold), particularly in males. Thus, fluctuations in V(15) clearly come from mortality change at young ages.
We now examine in more detail Japan, Canada, and the United States, which illustrate the main features of post-1947 mortality change in developed countries: relatively steady increase in life expectancy (Fig. S3, Online Resource 1) but large fluctuation in V (Fig. S4, Online Resource 1). We focus on the slowing of variance decrease and, in some regions, onset of variance increase in the 1980s. The United States in particular showed a striking variance increase in the early 1980s. The threshold ages were close to the conventional age of retirement, although there was a steady increase in thresholds over time—by a maximum of 28 years in Japanese females (Fig. S5, Online Resource 1).
Japan
Figure 6 shows how mortality change at young ages (below the threshold) and at old ages (above the threshold) generated the contrasting variance trajectories of each country.2 In Japan, each sex followed the same basic trajectory of variance change: a rapid decrease from 1947 to about 1975, and an increase after about 1990 (Fig. 6, panels a and b). The sexes differed in that V initially decreased faster for females, and the reversal from variance decrease to increase was earlier for females. Our decomposition shows that the initial variance decrease before 1977 was driven by the variance contracting effects of mortality decline at young ages, which dominated the effects of mortality decline at old ages (Fig. 6, panels a and b). Around the 1980s, these opposing effects reached a rough equilibrium, and thus V changed little. However, after about 1990, the negative effects of mortality decline at young ages weakened further, leading the positive effects of mortality decline at old ages to dominate. This shift in the focus of mortality decline to old ages consequently led V to increase (Fig. S7, Online Resource 1).
Canada and the United States
In Canada and the United States, the variance changes after 1947 were much smaller than in Japan (note the difference in y-axis scales in Fig. 6). Prior to 1983, Canada and the United States followed similar trajectories, each with little net variance change. However, after 1983, V increased and continued to fluctuate in the United States but began a rapid and consistent decrease in Canada. The result was that from 1983 to 2007, the Canadian variance (for females and males, respectively) changed from 8 % and 9 % lower than that for the United States to 20 % and 15 % lower.
We now focus on the period 1983–1994, which captures the major variance divergence between Canada and the United States (Fig. 6, panels c–f). In Canada, mortality decline at young ages produced percentage variance changes of −10.8 % for females and −10.1 % for males (Fig. 6, panels c and d). From old ages, the changes were 1.0 % in females and 2.9 % in males. In the United States, mortality change at young ages produced variance changes of −3.3 % in females and 3.6 % in males; and from old ages, 1.5 % and 4.8 %, respectively (Fig. 6, panels e and f). Thus, owing mainly to differences in male mortality change, the United States produced a larger component of variance increase from old ages but a much smaller component of variance decrease (and for males, variance increase) from young ages.
How did mortality change differ at young ages between Canada and the United States? In the latter, male mortality increased at ages 15–22 and 27–45, with increases greater than 30 % at 34–37 years (Fig. 7). U.S. females showed a pattern that was similar but of smaller magnitude (a maximum increase of 20 % at 35 years). By contrast, mortality increase for Canadian males was limited to ages 32–40, with a maximum increase of 17 %; mortality generally declined for Canadian females. The age-specific changes in mortality, therefore, differed most between Canada and the United States at young working ages, particularly among males. As a result, variance diverged sharply between Canada and the United States. When looked at in terms of life expectancy, this divergence is almost completely missed (Fig. S3, Online Resource 1). Thus, diagnosing mortality trends based on life expectancy alone is inadequate, and lifespan inequality should feature routinely in demographic monitoring.
Discussion
This article shows how change in lifespan inequality, as measured by V, depends strongly on the balance of mortality change around a young–old threshold. The threshold advances with increases in life expectancy, the modal age at death, and with the compression of mortality into a narrower range of ages. Before about 1950, changes to life expectancy and lifespan inequality had a strong negative correlation (Smits and Monden 2009; Vaupel et al. 2011), which arose because the emphasis of mortality decline was on ages below the threshold (Vaupel et al. 2011). Since 1950, lifespan inequality decrease has slowed and occasionally even reversed. We show that the post–WWII fluctuations in lifespan inequality were driven by fluctuations in mortality at young working ages, below the threshold age, whereas mortality decline was relatively consistent at old ages. The implication of these trends is clear: if mortality at young ages continues to fluctuate and mortality at old ages continues its steady decline, lifespan inequality increases will become more common.
But what drives these trajectories of age-specific mortality, causing them to vary both within and among countries? This question brings the focus of our attention to the social determinants of mortality (Graham 2009), and so to the realization that international divergence in lifespan inequality must largely be due to divergence in age patterns of the social determinants. Mortality is ultimately associated with education, income, social support (from family or public institutions, including the provision of healthcare), lifestyle, disease, and living conditions. These interact with the proximate, health-related causes of death at each age to generate lifespan inequality (Edwards and Tuljapurkar 2005; Nau and Firebaugh 2012; Shkolnikov et al. 2011). For example, Japanese development after 1947, including the start of universal healthcare in 1961, generated rapid mortality decline at mainly working ages. It is possible that this rapid progress against mortality gradually left the remaining causes of death in young adults in the category of those causes that are difficult to prevent. However, society—and hence the array of social determinants—was also changing, characterized by widening differences in mortality by education and income, particularly among working-aged males (Fukuda et al. 2004; Kagamimori et al. 2009). These social changes could also have contributed to the slowing of mortality declines in young adults: for example, if progress against the social determinants became limited to the most-educated or most-affluent.
A great deal of research is aimed at understanding why young adult mortality remains high in the United States compared with other high-income countries (Crimmins et al. 2011; IOM 2012). One source may be high geographic disparity in young adult mortality within the United States. For example, Cullen et al. (2012) showed that mortality differences below age 70 among U.S. counties and racial groups resulted largely from differences in education and income, particularly for males (see also Backlund et al. 2007; Crimmins et al. 2009). Current evidence also suggests that life expectancy differences between educational groups in the United States have widened in recent decades (Olshansky et al. 2012). A part of this variation is likely due to differences in healthcare access among young adults (Crimmins et al. 2011). Indeed, any explanation of trends in U.S. mortality must address the hypothesis that the correlation of social deprivation with low healthcare access raises the sensitivity of working-age mortality to macroeconomic change. In the United States, healthcare access at working ages depends largely on employer-provided health insurance; in 1994, 18.6 % of non-elderly adults in the United States had no health insurance (Holahan and Kim 2000). Being without health insurance limits care, particularly preventive care at young ages (Lasser et al. 2006), with evidence for consequently higher mortality (Wilper et al. 2009). The 1980s lifespan inequality divergence between Canada and the United States could be explained by such social factors: it is not possible to exclude the explanation that macroeconomic change resulted in more people in the United States in poor health and with no social safety net to ensure appropriate healthcare (Brenner and Mooney 1983; Siddiqi and Hertzman 2007). A slightly different understanding is gained by looking at the common causes of death at young, working ages (Harper et al. 2007; Nau and Firebaugh 2012). Harper et al. (2007) showed that in the United States in the 1980s, mortality among young adults rose, and the black-white gap in life expectancy increased because of differential increases in mortality from human immunodeficiency virus (HIV), heart disease, and homicide. HIV became prevalent in the 1980s and early 1990s, particularly among males aged 25–64, more so in the United States than in Canada (Armstrong et al. 1999; UNAIDS 2013). Nau and Firebaugh (2012) also highlighted heart disease and homicides as key contributors to the high variance of age at death in the United States. Heart disease is a leading cause of premature death; accidents and homicides, although being less common causes, also account for a high proportion of deaths at the youngest adult ages, where (as we show) the variance is highly sensitive to mortality change.
Alternate Inequality Metrics
Several established metrics of lifespan inequality exist (van Raalte and Caswell 2013). For the same mortality data, the young–old threshold can differ widely among these metrics—for example, by around 20 years, between V and the metric known as “lifespan disparity,” or e† (Zhang and Vaupel 2009). Our results indicate that the major post–WWII mortality changes occurred outside the zone of threshold disagreement among metrics, indicating that our qualitative conclusions are robust to the choice of metric. We use V for three reasons: it is easily understood and interpreted as a measure of dispersion, is easily decomposed (Edwards 2011; Edwards and Tuljapurkar 2005; Nau and Firebaugh 2012), and finds direct use in analyzing the demographic and economic consequences of mortality change (Edwards 2012; Schindler et al. 2012; Tuljapurkar 2008).
The Future
Because the young–old threshold in developed countries is now approaching 75–80 years (Fig. 2a), only mortality decline at the oldest retired ages can increase lifespan inequality. Given the ongoing fluctuation of social gradients in age-specific health and mortality, as well as the importance of social gradients for generating lifespan inequality (Cullen et al. 2012; Olshansky et al. 2012), we suggest that future work focus on the population-level effects of mortality change within specific social groups (Edwards 2011; Nau and Firebaugh 2012; Shkolnikov et al. 2011; van Raalte et al. 2011, 2012). The great good of development has been the consistent improvement of medical technology and care for the elderly, reflected in steadily declining old-age mortality (Vaupel 2010). However, our results suggest that without comparable progress in combating young-adult mortality, through action on the social determinants, mortality change is unlikely to follow the historical pattern of rising life expectancy and falling lifespan inequality. Hence, we should be prepared for increases in lifespan inequality to become a more common feature of demographic change.
Acknowledgments
This project is funded by the National Institutes of Health Grants AG22500 and AG039345 to Shripad Tuljapurkar, and by the Stanford Center for Population Research.
Appendix: Materials and Methods
Notes
V(0) is necessarily dominated by the (now usually small) fraction of infant deaths. If we set A = 15, the mean M(15) and the variance V(15) describe the dispersion of adult deaths. The advantage of focusing on adult ages is that the effects of infant mortality change are removed. Infant mortality has fallen steadily, driving steady declines in V(0) (Edwards and Tuljapurkar 2005; Tuljapurkar and Edwards 2011). Considering only mortality after particular index ages A can often reveal quite different trajectories of V(A) (Engelman et al. 2010). Even with low infant mortality, the inclusion of the few youngest ages can obscure the lifespan inequality effects of adult mortality change. This makes V(15) an ideal measure for investigating how the variability in age-specific mortality trajectories contributes to lifespan inequality change.
We also computed the components of variance change from below and above the fixed age of 65 years (Fig. S6, Online Resource 1). These components were near identical to those on either side of the shifting threshold, indicating that mortality change at ages near the threshold had minimal influence.
See the Background Information for each country on the HMD website (www.mortality.org).